World Bank IMF and Dev Agencies | |
World Bank IMF and Dev Agencies | |
792 VIEWS | |
![]() | |
PROSHARE | |
PROSHARE |
Wednesday, February 12, 2020 07:23 PM / by Deniz Igan, IMFBlog/ Header Image Credit:Intervision/World Pictures/Photoshot/Newscom
In Spain, private sector credit as a share
of GDP almost doubled between 2000 and 2007. This increase was accompanied by a
boom in housing prices-which doubled in real terms over the same period. The
economy as a whole also grew at a record pace.
But then in 2008, Spain's credit bubble burst, and with it came loan
defaults, bank failures, and a prolonged economic slowdown.
A less-noticed development in Spain was in the construction sector,
where employment grew by an astounding 47 percent, compared to the economy-wide
increase of 27 percent.
New IMF staff research, based on a large sample of
advanced and emerging market economies since the 1970s, shows that long-lasting
credit booms that featured rapid construction growth never ended well.
New evidence on credit booms
Rapid credit growth-known as "credit booms"-presents a trade-off between
immediate, buoyant economic performance and the danger of a future crisis. The
risk of a "bad boom"-where a rapid credit growth episode is followed by a
financial crisis or subpar economic growth-increases when there is also a boom
in house prices.
Our research shows that the experience with the dangerous combination of
credit booms and rapid expansion in the construction sector goes beyond the
Spanish borders and extends to time periods not related to the global financial
crisis.
We find that signals from construction activity may help to tell apart
the dangerous booms, which need to be controlled, from the episodes of buoyant
but healthy credit growth ("good booms").
Credit booms do not lift all boats alike
During booms, output and employment expand faster. But not all sectors
behave the same. Most of the extra growth is concentrated in a few
industries-specifically, construction and, at a distant second, finance.
However, the same industries that benefit the most during booms
experience the most severe downturns during busts. This implies that credit
booms tend to leave few long-term footprints on a country's industrial
composition.
Construction is special
Construction is the only sector that consistently behaves differently
between good and bad credit booms. On average, output and employment in the
construction sector grow between 2 and 3 percentage points more in bad booms
than in good ones. In all other sectors, the difference is smaller and not
significant (except trade, but only when it comes to output growth).
What makes construction special? Construction does not have the growth
potential of many other industries. In other words, too much investment in
construction may divert resources away from more productive activities and
result in lower output.
Also, the temporary boost in construction employment and the relatively
low level of skills needed may discourage some workers from investing in their
education and skills. This may have long-lasting effects on output after the
boom ends.
Finally, construction projects have large up-front financing needs, and
final consumers of the product (for example, houses or hotels) also tend to
borrow to finance their purchases. As a result, debt may increase significantly
more during booms led by construction.
The predictive power of construction
activity
An unusually rapid expansion of the construction sector helps flag bad
credit booms. A 1 percentage point increase in output and employment growth in
the construction sector during a boom raises the probability of the boom being
bad by 2 and 5 percentage points, respectively.
Construction growth is also a strong predictor of the economic costs of
bad booms than other variables. A 1 percentage point increase in output growth
in the construction sector during a bad boom corresponds to nearly a 0.1
percentage point drop in aggregate output growth during the bust.
Policy takeaways
If policymakers observe a rapid expansion in the construction sector
during a credit boom, they should consider tightening macroeconomic policies
and using macroprudential tools (such as higher down payments for mortgages).
In some cases, policy action will be triggered by other indicators, such
as house prices or household mortgages. Sometimes, however, these other
indicators may not sound the alarm (for example, because the construction boom
is financed by the corporate sector or by foreigners), yet risks accumulate.
Then, unusually rapid growth of construction could give a signal, for instance,
to impose limits on banks’ exposure to real estate developers and other
construction firms.
Finally, given that data on output and employment in the construction
sector are often available with a few months' lag, higher-frequency indicators
such as construction permit applications could act as valuable signals. Construction
indicators should also be included in models that assess risks to future
economic activity.
Related News